People on the
move. Looking for a better life. Willing to leave the kisses of their children
for months, years, maybe forever.
Migrants. Immigrants. The real movers and shakers of the world.
Whoa down! Not so easy.
Can’t just have all these people running around without some kind of
order. What about security, economic
order, even maintaining ethnic purity?
One answer, early twentieth century:
passports.
Along that same
vein of thinking and as the century progressed, states instituted increasing
degrees of control over the movement of people, ideas, and goods. These ideas included, for the US, containment
policy, which, with the best of intentions, would protect us all from
communism. Another idea was
international development.
The growth of
international development as an institution paralleled containment policy. Both born in the 1950’s or so, the idea of
containment was initiated by a fellow named George Kennan, quickly followed by
the Truman Doctrine. On their tailcoats
came the creation of the Peace Corps, approved by John F. Kennedy. Both focussed on containing people. On one hand, communists. On the other hand, all those rebellious poor
and potential migrants from poor countries.
The problem of
all those unruly ‘movers and shakers’ was exacerbated by the fall of the Berlin
Wall in 1989 and continued expansion of a globalized economy. Globalization, while great for corporate
interests, especially the international mobility of finance and capital
resources, also stirs up people. You
know, people, too, like to be mobile.
International
development and containment policy suffer an apparent contradiction. It is largely accepted that, in principle,
development promotes the concept of the democratic state in which it seeks
justice and qualitative improvements in the human condition. These improvements are especially focussed on
those with the least access to finance, capital resources, and means of
mobility.
However, the development
industry also accepts, or only mildly refutes, the basic tenets of
globalization like market liberalism, assumptions of economic scarcity and
competition, and materialism. In theory
market liberalism is innately egalitarian, that is, it harbours no human
prejudices. There is an assumption of a
kind of equality. We hear expressions such as an equal playing field and
comparative advantage.
It is well
documented that the reality is quite different.
In practice, the development industry is party to a structural disparity
between the world’s poor and wealthy. Disparity
means some have stuff and a lot of other folks do not. You have it, I do not, I do everything
possible to follow the rules to get there, I can’t, I get pissed off. Structural disparity is responsible for degradation
in general, of the economy, of the environment, of living conditions, and the many
kinds of political and physical violence which many people suffer.
Not far from
almost any development professional’s thought is a quantitative problem:
tensions arise between economic classes where capital resources are proportionally
diminishing and where the numbers of humans are increasing. Competitive tensions lead to many of the
world’s contemporary woes. In general,
this is understood to be a problem of economic scarcity to be treated with
market liberalization, that is, intervention and barriers should be minimalized
so that scarcity can be treated by comparative advantage and other laissez
faire mechanisms of the market.
Translated into lay terms this means to withdraw politically as far as
possible from economic activity, allow people to be free to buy and sell as
they please, social problems will generally work themselves out. The quantitative problem remains: how to
create more wealth to satisfy more people out of fixed resources in finite
material and biological world.
Oddly, mobility
and migration are assumed fundamentals to any liberal economy. Actually, it could be said that mobility is
the primary device of free trade. Money
can be invested anywhere. Technology can
be relocated. People can migrate.
So, too, does
the idea of growth underpin liberal economy.
Herein lies a complication.
Having accepted liberalized trade and globalization, one also must
accept consumption, unlimited wants, profit, and, in the end, the inevitable
competitive growth. Hmmm. Increasing numbers of people. Resources, both renewable and non-renewable,
diminishing proportionately and absolutely.
This is what we call a no-brainer.
A present, palpable, and profound problem. Growth in a no growth world. The planet is not getting any bigger. Non-economic competitive tensions are
unavoidable. Mobility necessarily
becomes a political issue.
Can’t just have
anybody migrating, now, can we?
The development
industry presents a rarefied, monolithic perspective on the world. We are always doing such good. Health improvements. Emergency relief. Mining companies cooperating with community
workers. We have such lovely words like
micro-credit, gender, sustainability, partnerships, entrepreneurialism,
eco-tourism, capacity building, strategic planning, management by results. We also offer that funny thing called
hope. Promises of improved soil
fertility, renewed forests, democratic reform, peace, equal rights between
women and men. Nice ideas, but why
always somewhere in the future?
Oof!
By and large, international
development institutions operate in any country they choose. They rarely, if ever, pay local taxes. They are not elected bodies. They are free to move as they wish. Obligations are short term, confined to projects,
nothing to do with governments, votes, or local taxes. Financial resources are spent on themselves
and the administration of their activities.
Meetings, conferences, annual leave, trainings, contract travel
expenses.
Actually, essential
to the business of development is the mobility of development itself. Development is free of the constraints of any
specific constituency and, therefore, free of democratic constraints. Development simply operates as it wishes.
Development
institutions contain people. They
promote the organisation of people into tiny collectives, like village groups
or interest groups. These lack size,
political status, or the resources to develop independent polities or
economies.
Development
institutions contain ideas. Ideas are
discussed and legitimized within the walls of their own profession.
Development
institutions contain the autonomous evolution of economies. The institutions flood local economies with cheap
credit and technologies. They steer
access to capital resources and production toward a world economy.
Development
institutions contain societies. They
co-opt as a universal cause the ideas of indigenous rights and traditional ways
of life. They treat the traditional as a
thing to be conserved. They imprison
peoples with development’s own ideas and theories of gender equality, civil
society, and democracy. Pluralism is
neutered.
International development,
as containment policy, serves to diffuse unrest and immobilize poorer
populations while an ever evolving global elite consolidates power.
Hi Jim. Thanks for the feedback. There is a kind of mythology about mobility. My normal experience, shared by many others, is that you can just hop on a plane and pretty much go anywhere you like. The impression of mobility is enhanced by the streaming of images and stories from other places through all our various media. Actually, it seems that only some 3% of the total human population every migrates permanently. Others move around a lot, but not far and not for long periods of time. It is odd how even 3% requires so many controls in this world.
ReplyDeleteThanks again. JP